DOC

THE DECLINE OF CIVIL SOCIETY AFTER POSTCOMMUNISM

By Carmen Nichols,2014-11-25 09:36
5 views 0
THE DECLINE OF CIVIL SOCIETY AFTER POSTCOMMUNISM

    THE DECLINE OF CIVIL SOCIETY AFTER POSTCOMMUNISM

    by David Ost

    to be included in Ulrike Liebert & Hans-Jörg Trenz, eds.,

     The New Politics of European Civil Society

     International discourse about the centrality of civil society to democracy owes much to the revival of the concept in Poland in the 1970s and 1980s. It was here that a newly emerging opposition deployed the concept, with its emphasis on everyday resistance to authoritarianism, as a way of rebuilding support after the post-Stalinist regime‟s devastating 1968-1970 attacks on

    political protests. The international renown bestowed upon the Solidarity movement in Poland, particularly in its initial 1980-81 heyday, sparked enormous interest in the theoretical concepts that inspired its democratic practice. Western political theory and international labor activism,

    1such as in South Africa, found a great deal in Solidarity not just to admire but to emulate. Here

    was a participatory, non-violent, democratic movement for social change in a society where formal political opposition was against the law. Moreover, the movement‟s focus on self-

    organized civic movements was able to survive the imposition of martial law, eventually putting Solidarity in the position to negotiate the end of communist party rule by the end of the decade. Democratic theory studied eastern Europe‟s vision of civil society for a long time. Even the

    booming interest in “social capital” theories of the 1990s likely owes much to the east European

    experience.

     All this came to a sudden end in 1989. Just when the dreams of the old civil society opposition appeared to be realized, its main east European theorists, now government leaders, abandoned their old participatory ethos. The trade union movement that had emerged in Poland as the bastion of democratic civil society went into deep decline, and it did so, paradoxically, in accord with the wishes of many of those very trade unionists. International interest in the democratic self-organization of society gradually moved away from a concern with eastern Europe. And with good reason. After 1989, the region‟s new leaders put the building of a market

    economy to the forefront of concerns, and came to see independent civic activity as dangerous insofar as it might raise questions and voice protests about how that process was being carried out. Also, market-building entailed a focus on creating the classes of a market economy: a propertied class endowed with capital and managerial prerogatives, a consumerist middle class,

    and a working class which, unlike that in the communist past, would no longer believe it had the clout and resources to have its interests met, much less a veto power to block moves it opposed. Democracy-building, meanwhile, focused on developing the parties that would compete for power and the institutional rules for state governance by no means insignificant tasks, but tasks,

    nonetheless, that did not call for engagement on the part of citizens. If the 1980s were a time when eastern Europe seemed to symbolize a mobilizing civil society, the 1990s could be seen as a revenge of the elite, although again, paradoxically, the elite doing the revenging was made up in large part of those who had formerly propelled themselves forward as the representatives of civil society.

     And what now? Where is civil society today? This article will argue that the new century has seen important signs of a return of an engaged civil society in eastern Europe, particularly in the trade union sphere, but that profound obstacles to its reemergence stem precisely from its abandonment in the early postcommunist years. In other words, I will argue that the obstacles to the reemergence of civil society today are due not to the legacies of communism, as some have

    2 but to postcommunism. It is in the postcommunist era that civil society was made weak: argued,

    first, by the former oppositionists who had promoted the concept and practice during the communist era, only to seek to marginalize it when they came to power; second, by the activities of trade unions, which cut back on their own activities just when the old regime fell and a capitalist economy emerged; and third, by the discursive decline of the concept of civil society in the postcommunist era (itself a product of the first two factors).

     The essays begins with a discussion of the origins of the concept of civil society and an account of how the original civil society theorists turned away from the idea. It then turns to an exploration of the situation of the trade unions, which had been key to the burgeoning civil society and which fell into serious decline afterwards. Finally, I discuss the discursive decline of “civil society” in recent years, leading to the reemergence of a concept in many ways antithetical to it, namely that of “nation.”

    The Rise and Fall of “Civil Society”

     “Civil society” was arguably the greatest theoretical contribution of the 1968-1989 east

    European revolutions. Until 1968, political opposition to communist rule mostly meant the fight

    2

    for a new government. Early postwar anti-communists had hoped for a new war to topple the Soviet-backed regimes; later “revisionist” opponents sought to usher into power a “true” socialist government against the “Stalinist deformations” of the present one. That method of opposition peaked, and crashed, in 1968, when a revisionist government came to power in Czechoslovakia, only to be crushed by Soviet invasion. In Poland, at the same time, the post-Stalinist Gomulka regime found itself challenged not by revisionists but by pro-communist nationalists, who then purged the revisionists through a well-orchestrated anti-intellectual and anti-Semitic campaign. Hope for state transformation no longer seemed possible. By the early 1970s, a cloud of hopelessness set over the political scene.

     A series of seminal articles by Polish oppositionists, and activism based on these ideas, introduced a notion of “anti-political” politics based on the idea of an activated civil society that

    would, in effect, challenge political power by ignoring it. This idea had its roots both in Polish traditions of self-governance during the era of partitions, most notably from the work of Edward Abramowski at the turn of the last century, and in the new social movements that emerged in the

    3 The latter had rejected Leninist vanguardist politics, and with their west in the 1960s and 1970s.

    Frankfurt School and Freudian New Leftism had argued that it wasn‟t political power but only a

    changed society that could bring emancipation. “Changed people change the world,” went the

    new slogan. This idea spoke even more deeply to east European political rebels than to their western counterparts, since the former could not enter the formal political world even if they wanted to. That, after all, was the lesson of 1968. Leszek Kolakowski anticipated the theory of civil society when he wrote, in 1971, that no matter how hopeless things appeared, there was always some room for some civic resistance, and that since it is always impossible to tell in

    4advance what the limits of a social system really are, all these opportunities should be pursued.

    Just as Herbert Marcuse had argued, at the end of One-Dimensional Man, that even in the face of

    a “totally administered society” in which people could barely even imagine an alternative future,

    5something must be done anyway “the Great Refusal,” Marcuse called it so Kolakowski

    insisted that no matter how hopeless the prospects for political reform, people must become active as if they believed that change was possible. That, after all, was the only condition to actually bring it about.

     Jacek Kuron and Adam Michnik pursued these ideas relentlessly in the mid-1970s as they sought to reestablish a formidable democratic opposition in Poland. In an important 1974 article

    3

“Political Opposition in Poland,” Kuron argued that the effort to preserve an independent culture

    apart from the state was not a prelude to real opposition but itself constituted a political

    6opposition. Here, for the first time, we have the idea that activity taking place within civil society alone, by people drawn together by a desire to freely engage in activities of their own choosing, could be the basis for a larger transformation of the polity. With Kuron, democratization becomes a goal that can be realized within society, not the state. Adam Michnik built on this insight to put forth a strategy we might call “anticipatory democracy,” or behaving in the present the way one would like to be able to do so in the future, acting today as if the desired tomorrow were already a reality. The idea was that political life becomes more democratic when people act as if it were democratic.

     In this view, any independent activity is thus a form of opposition. As Michnik put it in a seminal 1976 essay, “Every issue of public concern can be the basis for the rise of a social

    7movement. And these interlocking social movements, based solely on independent civic activity, would “change the world” in a democratic direction by getting people to act

    democratically in their daily lives now. Michnik and Kuron soon became the leading forces in the civic movement known as KOR, or the Workers Defense Committee, which was formed in late 1976 to defend workers persecuted for their role in protesting price hikes, and which quickly transformed itself into a loose-knit center coordinating and gathering and distributing information on independent civic activity. It was in cooperation with KOR that activists on the Baltic coast started organizing a “free trade unions” initiative, in which Lech Walesa soon

    became involved. Activists from this group called and led the August 1980 strikes that resulted in the formation of Solidarity.

     Solidarity was not created by Michnik and Kuron in fact, they opposed the

    shipworkers‟ insistence on independent trade unions because they believed it was unattainable

    but Solidarity, from its foundation in 1980 until the government‟s declaration of martial law in December 1981, acted in accord with their civil society precepts. The union served as the sponsor of a vast array of civic activities, not just trade unions but cultural associations, environmental clubs, independent schools, student clubs, farmers‟ organizations, factory

    newsletters. The 1980-81 period really seemed to be a time of “active participation on the part of citizens in egalitarian institutions and civil associations,” which Cohen and Arato see as key features of the civil society approach; indeed, the Solidarity experience was a key foundation

    4

    8 Even after the union was officially disbanded during martial upon which they built their theory.

    law, its leaders arrested and its resources confiscated, civic activity continued in Poland into the 1980s, laying the basis for the Round Table accords of 1989 that negotiated an end to the communist system.

     It might be thought that a society so engaged civically would be able not only to sustain but to broaden the independent public sphere once there were no more restrictions on it; once, in other words, a democratic political system construed the right to free public association as a given. In fact, however, this vision of civil society, as a struggle waged by vast civic participation against both state and market on behalf of a new vision of democracy, did not survive 1989. As a result of a number of factors the failure of the first Solidarity, the global

    embrace of neoliberalism in the 1980s, the actual fall of the communist systems and their reincorporation into the capitalist world system all the major “civil society” theorists

    abandoned their earlier understanding of the concept as a project of complete democratic openness, and gave it an entirely new meaning entailing little more than the building of a market economy. The emancipatory vision of civil society that was central to the pre-1989 opposition gave way to an ethos that privileged elite knowledge and economic transformation over civic participation. “Civil society” thus seemed to go moribund, slip into desuetude, soon after the communist era ended.

     In part, this resulted from an explicit turnaround on the part of Solidarity‟s political

    leaders, including both Michnik and Kuron, who, over the course of the 1980s, changed their

    9view on the question of what exactly the foundation of democracy really is. According to their

    earlier approach, manifested in the day-to-day practice of the initial Solidarity, democracy was premised on an engaged citizenry. People engaged in the daily effort of actively transforming their world were the only ones who could transform the world, and resist the pressures of state and market against active participation. According to the new approach, democracy hinged above all on property: only a sphere of social engagement with resources independent from the state, a sphere that the state was obliged to respect, could ensure the social space for civic activity that democracy required. Whereas the earlier approach argued that there could be no economic reform without political reform, the new approach argued that no political reform was possible without economic reform. Property-rights theory was the rage of opposition circles in the early 1980s after the declaration of martial law. Scarce underground publishing resources

    5

went into producing samizdat versions of the writings of Hayek. In 1985, Michnik himself

    published a harsh critique of the non-elite civic participation present in the first Solidarity movement, signaling his support for an elite pact without much non-elite input. Solidarity‟s

    political leaders of the late 1980s explicitly embraced radical market reform, jettisoning the idea of “self-government” many of them had supported in 1981. After coming to power in 1989, they moved quickly to introduce marketization policies, barely even giving the new democratic parliament time to read through all the new bills.

     Because they believed that most people would oppose their policies mistakenly, in fact,

    since all polls showed high support for market reform these former movement leaders-turned-

    elite decision-makers now wanted even less non-elite participation than before. The new Solidarity government adopted a tough shock therapy economic reform program, and considered opposition to it not only as wrong but as irrational. A new discourse of “reason” served to limit opposition to the new program and to send the unmistakable signal that civic participation was tantamount to the propagation of irrationality. The new liberal elite came to believe that there was one correct way of institutionalizing the market, and so scientific expertise needed to be valued over anything non-elites wished to contribute. As for Michnik and Kuron, both used their new positions Michnik as chief editor of the main daily Gazeta Wyborcza, Kuron as Minister

    of Labor to assure Solidarity members and other citizens that their interests would be served best by remaining quiescent and letting their new political leaders do what needed to be done

    take the measures to facilitate a swift transition to a capitalist economy. The old ideas, according to which democracy came about due to the everyday engagement of citizens in governing, were gone.

     All this constituted a monumental shift. By conflating civil society with bourgeois

    10 they were backtracking on their profound theoretical innovation separating the two. society,

    Indeed, it was just this separation that was at the heart of the East European contribution to democratic theory. Rejecting the classic Marxist conflation of the two, the east Europeans

    11claimed civil society as a terrain marked by openness, communication, and rational discourse.

    By defining civil society in this way and positing it as the heart of democracy, they were able to defend democracy both against orthodox Marxist charges that it was merely “bourgeois democracy,” and against free market apologists who considered private ownership a sufficient

    12guarantor of democracy. This was something quite new in the context of the Cold War

    6

    dichotomies of the time, which is why both the theory and, as carried out by the first Solidarity

    13 Now, however, movement, the practice were so important to western theorists of civil society.

    after 1989, when those same theorists spoke of building “civil society” they meant above all the building of a capitalist society, with primitive capital accumulation and class differentiation the most important goals of all.

     The consequence of intellectuals‟ new wariness of workers was to drive a wedge between

    middle-class reformers and non-elites. When former leaders of workers‟ movements proclaimed

    that their erstwhile comrades were not to be trusted, this gave license to others to distrust them. When Gazeta Wyborcza argued that workers were not rational participants in civil dialogue to resolve pressing social issues, it sent a signal that political debate ought to be carried out solely among elites. Instead of the open democracy they advocated when in opposition, a radically restricted debate is what they advocated now. Instead of an expansive public sphere and a flourishing civil society, this approach led to truncated debate in which only intellectual elites were supposed to participate. At least, this is what liberals hoped. In fact, as we know, it led to the rise of a populist political right instead, which was able easily to attack liberals as “hostile to the people.” Although this right is much more opposed to civil society than the liberals ever were, it gained in strength precisely to the extent that liberals sought to exclude workers from the ranks of acceptable civil society. As we will see, the victory of this tendency only shifted the discursive frame away from “civil society” and onto the trope of the “nation.”

    Labor and Civil Society

     When Solidarity‟s political leaders went off to government and into business after 1989,

    Solidarity as a trade union became the cornerpiece of civil society. Over time, of course, other institutions emerged: first there were Civic Committees, the precursors of political parties, and then parties themselves, which inspired some political activism. A competitive media world emerged, helping shape public opinion. Unions, however, were the institution best representing civil society as it had been during the heyday of the Solidarity period: with extensive participation and civic involvement. Though no longer able, as during the communist period, to resist the pressure of state and market, to be a site of civic participation apart from these two Poles, it nevertheless maintained the greatest amount of non-elite participation and enormous

    7

    symbolic prestige owing precisely to its role in the past. If anything like civil society in the previous sense was going to revive in the postcommunist period, it seemed that unions would play an important part in bringing it about.

     That, however, was not to happen. For it wasn‟t just Solidarity‟s intellectual leaders that abandoned the civil society paradigm. Trade union representatives also gave up their participatory ardor. The chief reason, of course, was their loyalty. For the past decade, Solidarity served not just as the representative of labor interests but of national interests. So who were trade unionists to now reject Solidarity‟s approach, once the latter‟s political leaders were now leading the government? But there was another factor too, linked to the diverse interests of different groups of unionists. For whereas unskilled workers were the group most dissatisfied with economic reforms, skilled workers tended to sympathize with the market reformers, at least as far as downsizing the workforce. With its full employment economy, the communist system hinged on massive hiring of unskilled and often unnecessary workers, whose retention under market conditions would hinder growth and profit. Skilled workers, who usually constituted the leadership of Solidarity, believed a leaner workforce to be in their interests: both materially, in increasing the chances for the firm to survive and become profitable, and professionally, in that they believed skilled work was likely to increase in prestige. The unions could not openly oppose the unskilled, often the majority of union members, but by refraining from union activism, and shunning the kind of civic organization they had encouraged when the Communists were in power, they could make sure that the market reformers had their way. As Solidarity leader Lech Walesa himself put it, at the moment when a Solidarity government came to power, “We will not

    catch up to Europe if we build a strong trade union.”

     Since Solidarity had been the key promoter of participation, this retreat by both its intellectual and labor pillars obviously had an impact in stanching civic enthusiasm. Two other factors also played an important role. The massive economic recession dampened participatory tendencies. Non-elites were wary of asserting their interests for fear of losing what they had. Second, the privatization of existing firms to foreign companies brought into the region a new type of hierarchical management style, which expressly sought to instill in workers the conviction of their own limitations, and presented the absence of influence from below as the

    condition for enterprise success. This was not a brutal management style but a paternalistic one. Workers who, under the state socialist system, often had to be involved in firm governance, if

    8

    only to deal with the difficulties of shortages and the imperatives of “storming” to meet the plan, were now placed in an explicitly subordinate position, categorized as “unthinking” and

    14“inflexible.” The new management style insisted on non-participation as a key to economic growth, and in the initial postcommunist period, most people were ready to agree.

     What happened to unions in the postcommunist period? They declined precipitously on all possible levels: membership, density, workplace influence, and bargaining power. They were not simply pushed into a period of decline, union leaders themselves oversaw this decline, as few of them were interested in building up their unions. A 1999 article that I co-authored with Marc Weinstein was titled “Unionists Against Unions.” Based on a survey of union leaders in 95 industrial firms throughout Poland, we found that unionists believed in the sanctity of property rights, supported extensive managerial prerogatives and limited employee input in private firms, and saw support for market reform as one of the main reasons for their involvement in union

    15work. Instead of pursuing union work, Solidarity pursued politics instead not “labor” politics,

    but all-purpose right-wing, conservative politics, following both the predilections of union leaders, and the desire of right-wing politicians outside of parliament for an institutional base to give them some clout. As I argue extensively in my 2005 book, The Defeat of Solidarity, this

    right-wing turn also followed largely from the abandonment of labor politics by Solidarity‟s

    16former leaders, now leading liberal politicians. By the end of the 1990s, Solidarity had

    “succeeded” in becoming a major political actor: the coalition party led by Solidarity, “Solidarity Electoral Action,” was the dominant partner in the government, with Solidarity chairman Marian Krzaklewski the political kingmaker. But this only hurt the union movement even more: Solidarity was now seen by most people simply as the government, responsible for all the continuing painful economic reforms. By 2001, local union officials succeeded in breaking the official connection between union and party, but more damage had been done. Union membership by this time had plummeted to under a million, its influence at an all-time low.

     Since about the beginning of the new century, five factors have emerged to favor a union revival: survival imperatives of the union bureaucracy, incorporation into the European Union, emerging international labor solidarity, a new generation of laborers, and the end of postcommunism in the firm, creating new challenges for unionists. Together, these factors appear to signal the emergence of a new subjectivity that is key to the revival of an active civil society.

    9

     As for survival imperatives: put simply, today‟s union officials can no longer afford to

    neglect their own unions. In the initial postcommunist era, they could. For most of the 1990s, union leaders had relative autonomy from their base, both for the resources they controlled and the exit options at their disposal. As for resources, although membership was declining, it was doing so from a level of near universal membership, and so still quite high. In 1995, union

    density in the ten eastern EU member states was over 40%, about a third higher than in the

    17 Because they also former EU-15; it was only in the next decade that the ranking would reverse.

    still controlled access to services such as vacation resorts and summer camps, they could be inactive in defense of their members without jeopardizing their access to union resources. In recent years, though, membership has plummeted and easy access to resources has disappeared, thus requiring union officials to be more responsive to their base. As for exit options, the period of rapid mobility from union official to government position is over. If today‟s union officials are

    going to maintain their relatively good jobs, they need to do so as union officials, which requires

    greater commitment than in the past.

     Second, there is the role of the European Union. The EU has long treated unions as a constitutive part of the European political economy, an essential actor in the “social partnership”

    regime that EU rules mandate. Even while the individual EU-15 countries were trying to cut back on the influence and prerogatives of their own trade unions, it provided both money and personnel to promote union education programs in the east, and to facilitate contacts of eastern unionists with their western counterparts. The EU has funded numerous programs instructing postcommunist states on the details of European social partnership and training unionists to take

    18part. Incorporation into the EU seems to mean that unions in the east are condemned not just to

    19survive but to be active.

     Third, emerging labor solidarity. Because of the free flow of capital within the European Union, western trade unions have become very active in building ties with unions in the east, seeing solidarity as necessary for the defense of their own standard of living too. In recent years, German unions have been helped auto workers in eastern Volkswagen and Opel plants to establish successful unions, while British retail workers‟ union has been active in organizing the

    east‟s new “hypermarkets.” Eastern workers have begun returning the favor, such as by

    committing themselves to the fight against the Bolkestein Directive on the liberalization of the

    10

Report this document

For any questions or suggestions please email
cust-service@docsford.com